[Assam] Essay by Sanjib Baruah
Chan Mahanta
cmahanta at charter.net
Fri Feb 27 12:01:06 PST 2009
*** What do netters think?
cm
_____________________________________________________________________________
Eastern Quarterly
(Publication of the Manipur Research Forum, Delhi)
Vol. 5, Issue I, April - June 2008, pp. 61-65
'A Road, Smooth and Sleek like a Snake': Development and the
Rhetoric of Vision
Sanjib Baruah
"The World Bank will be replacing the old rundown road with a new
road that will be smooth and sleek like a snake."
-Zoramthanga, Chief
Minister of Mizoram
Zoramthanga's choice of metaphor, though wonderfully resonant with
the Northeast Indian landscape, is perhaps unusual. But to readers
of 'vision statements' about the region's future, the spirit may be
familiar. Development in this genre of writing, like Zoramthanga's
image of a road of the future, is a fantasized object, not a
realistic vision of the future that people can relate to.
The editors of Eastern Quarterly [EQ] deserve our gratitude for
organizing a discussion on a new document, Peace, Progress and
Prosperity in the North Eastern Region: Vision 2020, put together by
the National Institute of Public Finance and Policy [NIPFP] and
brought out under the auspices of the Ministry of Development of
North Eastern Region.
B. George Verghese, one of the authors of Vision 2020, opens the EQ
discussion. "The stage appears now to be reasonably well set," he
writes, "for a major thrust forward. Things are changing and there is
ground for cautious optimism. Development and opening up to its
neighbours could provide impetus for the next stage." In contrast to
the radical views of the other contributors, Verghese's approach
might seem conventional-though his ideas on institutional reforms are
anything but that. I will refer to those proposals later in the
essay. He estimates that the Northeast will have to grow by 12 to 13
percent every year in per capita income and basic social indices, if
it were to catch up with the rest of India by 2020--assuming a 9 per
cent growth rate for India. "Closing the gap," he believes, "will not
be easy but is doable." However, the centre will have to make major
investments.
Contrast this way of thinking about development to that of Prasenjit
Biswas who rejects the very idea of a region lacking development.
The idea of "lack," he says, "is not simply a negative idea, it is
rather a complex outcome of developmental practices." On a similar
note, Rohan D'Souza rejects the foundational notion of economic
backwardness. Once the absence of markets is "declared to be
indicative of backwardness," it "leads almost automatically to the
desire for markets for development."
Politics of Representation
The major question that Biswas, D'Souza and others raise is this: Can
development theory and practice ignore the politics of
representation? I mean 'representation' both in the political sense,
and in the sense of ways of seeing, and portraying. The way we
represent poverty and underdevelopment has consequences. Some of our
official categories and those of the social sciences - Economics in
particular - are good at capturing certain realities, but not others.
Let us take the example of a poor community with a degree of reliance
on a public lake where people fish. We can see the people as a
community that survives, using a mix of market and non-market goods.
Or we can see them as part of an aggregated mass of people "living
below the poverty-line." If taking the latter view, a development
agency decides to finance commercial fishing--even on a modest
scale--it could make one or two people rich, a few more would find
employment, but many more people might be worse off if they catch
fewer fish, because of the mechanized fishing methods now in use in
the same water. In terms of basic nutrition, they would be
worse-off. Theoretically, the dynamism that the new enterprise could
bring to the local economy might in future compensate for that. But
the stakes are simply too high to take leave it at that.
Development, in my view, is not just one thing: self-evident and
predictable. It is not good or bad in some a priori sense. If it is
about removing major sources of un-freedom, "poverty as well as
tyranny, poor economic opportunities as well as systematic social
deprivation," we must ask very concretely, whether it enables or
restricts freedoms and capabilities. These questions must be asked
about each and every intervention that claims development as its
goal. The answers will not be easy: inevitably, there will be winner
and losers. But at least one thing is obvious. The state should not
regard itself, to use Monirul Hussain's words, as the "development
giver," and treat the people as "development takers." And since
increasingly, the central government is the major source of funds for
the development of the region, and the bureaucrats in Delhi are key
players, questions of voice and representation are more important
than ever.
It is not enough to point at elections, and ignore substantive
questions about representation. "The restless and discontented," says
Verghese, "fall prey to adventurism and subversion." Others
understand the strength and persistence of insurgencies, at least
partly, in terms of the diffuse presence -- in the background -- of
an inchoate constituency that feels un-represented. Let us assume for
the moment that Verghese is right. But does it allow the authors of
Vision 2020 to go from there, and make a set of assertions implying
that it is what, the people of the Northeast want? As Rohan D'Souza
suggests insightfully, the authors of the NIPFP document appears to
have the remarkable ability not only to speak for the people of the
Northeast, but what the people want, happens to match exactly with
what these "visionaries" want to see in the region.
The Pagladia Dam and the Politics of Development Finance
Monirum Hussain's account of the protests against the
on-again-off-again Pagladiya Dam project in Assam brings out the
politics of development finance. The dam is likely to displace more
than one hundred thousand people from agricultural lands and homes.
Originally conceived as far back as 1968, it has been shelved a
number of times because of grassroots opposition--but only to be
brought back later when the political climate changes. At each phase
of confrontation between the state and the protesters, an
extraordinary gap becomes evident between official and local
knowledge. The area where initially, the government intended to
settle the displaced people was officially "vacant," but the people
about to lose their land found out that the land was already
occupied, albeit "illegally." Among the people that would be
displaced by the project are some that lack legal documents to prove
property ownership. The protesters knew only too well the reality of
bureaucratic practice; that it would be hard to resettle and
compensate those without proper land documents.
The interesting question that arises is this: why has the state and
its agency, the Brahmaputra Board, been so persistent? The answer
that emerges from Hussain's study is simple, but quite revealing and
persuasive. The government agencies --and the contractors lobby-seem
to salivate at the prospects of laying their hands on the money
allocated to the project by the central government. For politicians,
the patronage possibilities that large sums of money open up far
outweigh any other consideration. Hence, the persistence in efforts
to revive the project.
International Finance Comes to Northeast India
If one goes by this insight, things are only likely to get worse,
suggests Ramananda Wangkheirakpam. The coming of international
financial institutions such as the Asian Development Bank [ADB] and
the World Bank, he fears, could only mean growing "disempowerment and
helplessness of the people in the region." The ADB, he points out,
has completed technical assistances studies on sectors including
tourism, roads, urban development, waste management, waterways and
governance. Their entry could mean that, decisions that would impact
millions of lives would be made in places, much further than New
Delhi. Drawing on his experience as an activist, he writes, "getting
access to key policy and project documents now requires writing to
Manila and/or Washington DC and to complain against a project one
might need to even spend meagre resources to go to these Headquarters
to meet project officials."
A Reform/Revolution Debate?
If D'Souza radically challenges the very idea of development, Biswas
while sharing some of the vocabulary of post-development thinking,
has instincts that are Marxist in a more familiar sense. He is
concerned that Vision 2020 seeks to reproduce "capitalist relations
of reproduction," and the language of comparative advantage simply, a
way of making the natural resources of the region available to global
markets. His alternative does not threaten the old left-liberal
consensus on development. The focus, be believes, must be "on
improving economic condition for the poorest, through the creation of
economic growth opportunities." That would require "structural
change": a shift of employment opportunities from agriculture to
industry and service.
Thingnam Kishan Singh is radical in his reading of colonial economic
history. During that period, he says, economies of Northeast India
went through "a transition from its various pre-capitalist social
formations to a quasi-capitalist organization of productive forces."
When it comes to options today, however, he too settles for
conventional left-liberal answers. He accepts that a low gross
domestic product is not "congenial for improving the living
conditions of the people" and "people in areas with low per capita do
not live well." He advocates strategies that would develop a
production base that uses the region's resources to benefit its
people.
As I have indicated, Verghese's proposals for institutional reforms
are innovative. Northeasterners should not shy away from debating
them. He proposes ending Inner Line and Restricted Area permits. He
recommends Trusteeship Zones for disputed areas between Assam and
Arunachal, as sites for "railheads, airstrips, communication hubs,
warehouses, cold storages, entrepots, [and] training centres." He
proposes expedited cadastral surveys of land in hill areas, and
non-territorial electoral constituencies for workers brought in from
outside the state to work.
Development and the Democracy Deficit
The discussion in EQ brings out sharply one major weakness in our way
of trying to develop Northeast India: the region's democracy
deficit-a consequence of decades of insurgency and
counter-insurgency. Sources of funds being sources of power, and
development financing becoming a way of imposing other people's
priorities, are not unique to Northeast India. But observers far
less radical, than the contributors to this issue of EQ, have been
struck by how democracy deficit presents unusual difficulties for
development projects in Northeast India. A World Bank Strategy
Report, for instance, finds "the paternalism of central-level
bureaucrats, coercive top-down planning, and little support or
feedback from locals" to be the principal obstacle to the utilization
of the region's vast water resources for sustainable development.
These observers are struck by the extraordinary phenomena of
potential beneficiaries of embankment projects, opposing them. There
is deep distrust of the central government's development-oriented
institutions like the Brahmaputra Board. As the World Bank report
puts it, local stakeholders in the Northeast simply do not believe
that most developmental initiatives are designed to benefit them.
Indian elites do not like to acknowledge that. Thus our bureaucrats
and politicians quote World Bank reports on many other matters-mostly
when they appear to authorize more money--but not when it comes to
this crucial political insight. It is unlikely therefore that the
radical voices represented in this issue of EQ, will get the
attention they deserve. Given this state of denial in our national
public intellectual life, vision statements about Northeast India's
future, like the epigraph at the beginning of this essay, are bound
to sound like the marketing pitch of salesmen selling snake oil.
More information about the Assam
mailing list